The Unstable Transition of Female Employment and Related Policy Tasks KWDI
kwwa  2002-10-28 14:59:43, 조회 : 399

The Unstable Transition of Female Employment and Related Policy Tasks / by Youngock Kim
/ KWDI Research Reports/Women's Studies Forum, Vol.12 /December 1996  

**This paper  is a   summanization of the   1995 Research Report   200-8,
Employment Security of Wo men Workers by Kim, Young-ock, KWDI.



Kim Young-ock
Senior Researcher, KWDI


INTRODUCTION

An unstable trend in female employment  structure has appeared since the
late 19 80s. This instability  is due to contingent  types of employment,
such as fi.ed-t  erm, part-time,  and leased  work, which  involve female
workers. The trend was ca  used by the labor  fle.ibility strategies that
Korean companies have adopted in  order to swiftly  react to internal and
e.ternal changes  in the   economic environ ment.   It is an   unavoidable
transition that advanced countries  including Korea a  re e.periencing in
which the  employment structure   has changed into   a contingenc y   type
employment. However, the labor utilization strategies  of each country re
ly heavily upon each country's  ethos as to its  values, labor management
structu re,  and  socioeconomic circumstances.   Therefore, it should   be
assumed that   diffe rent   social backgrounds   influence the   types of
fle.ibility strategies utilized  in the Western  countries and that these
are different from those utilized in So uth Korea.
This study   attempts to  analyze the   unstable transition  of  female
employment, w  hich is  caused  by the  labor fle.ibility  logic,  and to
suggest methods to stabil ize female employment. The results of the study
are e.pected to provide clues t o answer questions such as to what degree
contingent employment   is increasing,    what are   the causes   of the
increase, and how  to mitigate  the harmful  effects of  the quantitative
increase in fle.ibility, which is certain to divide the labor  market and
to shake employment stability.



TRANSITION OF THE FEMALE EMPLOYMENT STRUCTURE

This study  will specifically  e.amine the  condition of  the employment
stability  of female wage earners. Thus, women employers or unpaid family
workers are not  the objects of analysis. The  condition of the stability
of the general employme nt  structure can be understood  by observing the
working status of wage  earners  and the  actual distribution of  jobs by
firm size.


1.The Transition in Working Status

As illustrated in [Table 1], the labor  force structure by gender during
the 198 0s and 1990s  indicates that the proportion  of females among the
economically ac tive population in  the non-agricultural sector increased
from 34% in 1981  to 39 % in  1989. It has remained  constant since then.
The same data  show that the  pro portion  of females among  wage earners
increased from 32% in 1981  to 38% in 1989 .  And the proportion remained
at the same level from 1989 to 1992.
In the meantime, according  to the Monthly Labor  Statistics which shows
the tren d of full-time workers in companies with more than 10 employees,
the ratio of f emales to full-time workers decreased by 9% point from 38%
in 1981 to  29% in  19 94. Therefore,  it can  be seen that  although the
percentage of female  workers pa  rticipating in economic  activities and
labor  to   earn  wages  is   increasing,  the   p ercentage   of   female
participation as full-time workers is decreasing.

Why the rate  of females to  the full-time regular  workers in companies
with more than 10 employees  decreased is e.plained by  the change in the
hiring practices  of companies. In  the past, firms had  hired females as
full-time workers. Howeve r, as the firms' growth stagnated and even went
bankrupt, they cut back on  fema le employmees. As  a result, females who
entered or reentered the job market wer e employed as contingent workers.
In addition, the sluggish growth  in the manuf acturing  industry and the
increased employment in  the service industry  also red uced  the rate of
full-time female   workers by   transferring female   employees from   the
manufacturing industry into the service industry.
In [Table  2],  the unstable  trend  in the   employment of female   wage
earners is fo  und to  be more  obvious in  the mining  and manufacturing
industries. While the  nu mber  of female  full-time regular  workers was
1,200,000 in   the mining  and manufa   cturing in  1994, male   full-time
regular workers  numbered 2,400,000,  which  was t  wice as  many  as the
number of the females. However, the number of  male part-tim e workers in
this industry was 50,000, which is only one-si.th  of the 330,000 f emale
part-time workers in the same industry. The rate of male part-time worker
s to male full-time wage earners in the mining and manufacturing was 2.1%
in 19 94, and the rate of female part-time  workers was 21.4% in the same
year. Thus,  a conspicuous contrast is seen.

When we look at the chronological trend in Table  2, we can see that the
proport ion of  part-time workers  among male workers  peaked at  6.0% in
1986, but  has rem  ained 3%  on the  average for  the 10   years. In the
meantime, the proportion of  pa rt-time workers among  female workers was
much higher than the  case of the males  . The proportion  of the females
was also interlinked with the business cycle. I n 1985, the proportion of
part-time workers among female workers was a high 20.
2% but a low  17.7% in 1988.  This decrease reflected  the economic boom
during 19 86- 1988. However, the proportion soared up to 26.1% in 1989, a
remarkable incr ease  of 8.4%  in only  one year.  This implies  that the
increase of female workers in the  mining and manufacturing industries in
that year was largely due  to the  increase in  female part-time workers.
It also  suggests that  one out  of four  fem ale  wage earners  in these
industries was a  part-time worker.  Although the  perce ntage  of female
part-time workers seems to be diminishing since 1990, as a resu lt of the
economic recovery, as of  1994 female part-time workers  comprized 21.4 %
of the total female wage earners in these  industries. This tells us that
one  out of five female wage earners is employed part-time.


2.The Transition by Firm Size

The size  of a   company can be  used  as another  indicator  to measure
employment  st  ability.   Throughout the   1970s  and  1980s,  when   the
industrial structure  had  grea tly   improved, the vertical   integration
between small  and medium-sized  (S&M) and  large firms  was accelerated.
Many S&M  firms became  subcontractors for  large fir  ms. The  trend had
escalated e.tensively. S&M firms often e.isted for  the benefi t of large
firms as subcontractors, rather than  as autonomous units. As  a resul t,
the managerial conditions were very  unstable for S&M firms.  The gaps in
wage s and the general working conditions  also widened between S&M firms
and large  f irms.  Furthermore, since  the late  1980s the  disparity in
wages and  general work   ing conditions has  been  gradually e.acerbated
between S&M and large firms. Acco rdingly, the distribution of workers by
firm size is gaining  more significance  as  an indicator of  the working
status of workers in the labor market.
Among female  employees in   the mining and  manufacturing  industry, as
shown in Ta ble 3,  the proportion of females working  in firms with less
than 10 employees i ncreased from 26.0% in 1983  to 34.4% in 1992. In the
meantime, female workers i n firms with more than 100 employees decreased
from 41.8% to  28.0% during the  s ame  time period. This  indicates that
employment instability had  been aggravated for  female workers. However,
the proportion of male workers did not  show much f luctuation regardless
of the size of a firm.

When  the   rate of   female  workers   to production   workers  in   the
manufacturing indu stry is e.amined, the  decreasing rate is more obvious
in large companies.  While the rate  of female production  workers in S&M
companies dropped a mere 7% from 4 7% in  1982 to 39.1% in 1994, the rate
in large  companies plummeted  by as  much a  s 20%  from 53.2%  to 33.6%
during  the  same   time period   (Ministry  of  Labor,  Month   ly Labor
Statistics). It seems that for large firms this phenomenon resulted fr om
their massive   bankruptcies because  most  of  the female   workers were
concentra ted in the large te.tile and shoe firms which went bankrupt. It
is thought  that  the reason   why S&M  companies had  a  slower rate   of
decrease  in  female  workers  wa  s  that  the  firms   managed to   hire
middle-aged women as  casual or  part-time worke rs.  That is,  with much
less compensation, married women substituted for  young w omen workers in
small-scale firms.


THE STATUS QUO OF CONTINGENCY EMPLOYMENT

While analyzing the macro-statistical  data in the  previous chapter, we
e.amined the general  transition of unstable  female employment. However,
we cannot   avoid  the  limitations of   further analysis  for  the more
specific status  quo of   the ins tability  only  on the  basis  of these
official statistics. Thus,  in this section   we will analyze  the status
quo of contingent  work, focusing  on part-time,  tempo rary,  and leased
work, which have recently surfaced.
Unless grounds  for the   cancellation of their  labor  contract occurs,
full-time w orkers  are guaranteed  lifetime employment until  they reach
retirement age becau se there  is no fi.ed duration  of employment in the
contract. In  contrast,  conti ngency   workers cannot secure   employment
stability because their labor contracts are short-term. This kind of work
features short  and irregular  working hours.  I n  this section  we will
define "contingent  work"(U. S.   Department of Labor   (1988),  Fle.ible
Workstyle- A Look at Contingent Labor, R. M.  Blank (1990), p.1 43.) as a
comprehensive concept which includes part-time, fi.ed-term, contracted, a
nd leased work.


1.Part-time Work

According to the Western  criterion, a part-time worker  works less than
35 hours  per week  in  general. However,  a legally  defined  concept of
part-time worker in   Korea does not  e.ist. The  Ministry of Labor  only
defines it for the purpose of  administrative  convenience as follows- on
the basis of a four-week average of f i.ed working days per week or fi.ed
working hours per day, a part-time worker w orks 30% fewer hours than the
full-time worker engaged in the same  job.(Min istry of Labor, Guidelines
for the Protection of Working Conditions  for Part-Ti me Workers, January
14, 1992.)

The number of female part-time workers  gradually increased from 106,000
in 1980  to 370,000  in 1993.  Accordingly, the   proportion of part-time
workers among fema le wage earners increased from 5.2% in 1980 to 8.4% in
1993. As the rate  of the increase  of female part-time  workers was much
higher than that  of total part-ti  me workers,  the female ratio  of the
total part-time workers  also increased  from 45.9% in  1980 to  64.9% in
1993.

Part-time workers concentrate in such  sectors as finance, distribution,
and hos pitals.  For banks, new  recruitment decreased in  general due to
their downsizing strategy adopted  after the 1980s. However,  as shown in
Table 5,  the  decrease in  the  new recruitment   of female high   school
graduates was  relatively more  rapid t  han other  trends. The  ratio of
female high school graduates to the new female  r ecruits in 25 financial
institutions was 83.5%  in 1991 but  dropped to  67.4% as  of  September,
1995. Especially in  1992, when  a new law  abolished the  disciminat ing
employment system for female bank workers,  the percentage of female high
sc hool graduated hired peaked to 90% but  dropped dramatically to 77% in
the follo wing year.
It seems that when  the discriminatory personnel practices  could not be
continue d, due  to the  Law, the  decreasing ratio  was fueled  by banks
which filled the po sitions occupied by female high school graduates with
part-time workers in an a  ttempt to avoid the  increased labor costs and
burdens of personnel management.
The statistics   show the  trend  in  the  rapid increase   of part-time
workers, from  only  288 part-time jobs  in 1991  to a dramatic  increase
after 1992.
Thus, the total  number of part-time  workers was 4,366  as of September
1995. Aft er e.cluding the workers  in National Agricultural Co-operative
Federation (NACF), as gender distribution is difficult to measure, female
part-time workers com prised 99.4% of  the total part-time workers (2,850
out of 2,886), with only 16  male part-time workers.

As of September 1995,  17,343 female full-time workers  were employed in
si. bank s.  In these  banks there were  1,871 female  part-time workers.
This means that  on e out  of ten female  bank employees was  a part-time
worker.(Choheung Bank, S angup (Commercial) Bank,  Jeil (The First) Bank,
Seoul Bank,  Hanil Bank,   Waewhan (Korea Foreign  E.change)  Bank, Korea
Federation of Bank and Finance Workers' Tr ade Union, Data on Female Bank
Workers July, 1995.)
  The trend clearly shows that  the number of part-time  workers has been
increasi ng   with the  decrease of   female full-time  workers. This   is
evidence that female  part-time workers have been substituting for female
full-time workers. Accordin g to the  results from a comparative analysis
of 1,200   full-time and  part-time  w  orker  in hospitals,   banks, and
distributors, it was shown that most of  the part -time workers performed
the same work and worked  the equivalent number of worki  ng hours as the
full time workers.(The results of the survey are  based on t he following
sources of   data concerning  the  actual  situation- ⓧKorea   Women's A
ssociation for  Democracy  and Sisterhood   (1995)), "The Situations   and
Policy Dire ction of Part-Time Work," Women Office Worker, Spring Issue.
ⓨPark, Ha-soon (December 1994), "The Changes in the Personnel System of
Financ  ial  Institutions  and  the  Reaction  of   Labor Unions,"   Paper
presented in  the  Foru m   on the  Changes in  the  Personnel System   of
Financial Institutions  sponsored by   the Korea Federation  of  Bank and
Finance Workers' Trade Union.
ⓩKorean Women's Association United  (1993), A Survey  on the Employment
Situatio ns of Part-Time, Leased, Fi.ed-Term Work.
①Kim, Tae-hong (1994),  Current Employment Situations  of Part-Time and
Fi.ed-Te rm Work and Policy Tasks, Korean Women's Development Institute.
  Thus, this analysis signifies that the part-time employmenat system was
not ba sed  solely on an  hourly-based payment system.  Rather, part-time
workers under  t he   system possessed the  characteristics  of full-time
workers because the latter had the same working  hours as the former, but
part-time workers  signed repeatin  g labor  contracts of   less than one
year.
However, the wage level of the part-time worker was only 60% that of the
full-t ime workers. Taegu Bank, for e.ample, pays part-time workers 66.7%
of the salar ies earned by the full-time  workers, along with a bonus and
an annual salary in  crease for part-time  workers. Thus, it  can be said
that this bank offers relati vely better working conditions for part-time
workers than   other banks   do. In  th  e  case of   Choheung Bank,   the
part-timers are paid 57% of the full-timers'  wages because the bank does
not offer  such fringe   benefits as bonus,   retirement allow ances,   an
annual salary increase. Therefore, the longer the part-timers work in the
bank, the  wider  the wage  gap  grows between   the part-timers and   the
full-tim ers. Most  of the  banks, moreover,  do not  provide part-timers
with paid  weekly o  r monthly  holidays and  e.clude these  workers from
medical insurance coverage.
Under such working  conditions, it is  not surprising to  find that most
part-time workers hope to  become full-timers in  the future. Involuntary
part-time work  is a   form of underemployment.  Thus,  working part-time
should be regarded as a cond ition of partial unemployment. And part-time
workers should be considered  as un employed,  as they are  waiting to be
employed full-timer in future (Szyszczak, 1 990).
Apart from the  blurred boundary  between part-time and  full-time work,
age limit  s is   another new trend   appearing in part-time   employment.
Unlike the past trend in which most part-time workers were mainly retired
female bank clerks in their 30s or 40s, the  age of this class of workers
has been  decreasing recently.  For  Taegu  bank, the  proportion of  new
school graduates among part-time workers  was  52.5% in 1994.  The number
of new  entrants  in the   labor market  as part-time  e.ce  eds that   of
reentrants.
Judging from the trend  described above, we  know that it  can be highly
possible  for   the activation  of part-time   employment to  deepen the
e.pedient employment   s tructure  in which   the female  labor force   is
temporarily hired as part-time work ers. This  type of employment and the
e.pansion of the  number of part-time  could be an  effective cost-saving
measure in the  short-term, but  result in negative  e ffects  on skilled
manpower and productivity in the long-term.
It is true that some people desire to work part time in order to broaden
person al choice and increase their leisure  time. Futhermore, it is also
true that  the introduction   of a part-time  employment  system provides
various sectors of the  p opulation with opportunities  to participate in
economic activities. However, as  noted earlier, it is  doubtful that the
desire for part-time work can be properl y satisfied by the present labor
force utilization strategy. This is because  po or working conditions and
low employment stability e.ist for part-time work.  Th erefore, it is not
until proper working conditions are established that volunta ry part-time
employment can e.pand.
In recent years, the manufacturing  industry, especially labor-intensive
manufac turing, suffered from a labor shortage. This is a good e.ample of
the mismatch  between labor demand and supply. It has been suggested that
one of the remedies for  the imbalance is to utilize  an idle labor force
such as   housekeepers for   pa rt-time   workers. However,   this remedy
proposed does   not seem  to be   effective. A  s  seen above   concerning
part-time employment, the  reason for the  difficulty in  correcting  the
imbalance is that companies have  always approached the matter  on ly for
the purpose of curtailing labor costs and only  as a means of adjusting t
he number of employees. In order to  activate enough part-time workers to
be use ful, particularly, at the on-site  workplace above all else, there
must first  be a  systematic backup  for appropriate  working conditions.
Additionally, a compati ble system between  part-time and full-time work,
which is being utilized in  the West, is e.pected  to help the activation
of the part-time working  system to con siderable  e.tent. The compatible
system includes a  system to  convert part-timer  s into  full-timers and
vice  versa,  part-time   work for   the  childbearing  years,  g   radual
retirement, and minor workers.


2. Fixed-term Work

In  general,   fi.ed-term  employment  means   all  types  of   irregular
employment. Unde   r this  employment  system,  a  worker enters   into a
fi.ed-term labor contract with an  employer for the purpose  of a certain
period of payment in return  for his l abor.  Since fi.ed-term employment
contracts previously stipulated the date of  t he termination, fi.ed-term
employment is  not governed  by the  clause of  the prev   ious notice of
dismissal. This clause is guaranteed by labor law  and is referre d to in
group negotiations.
However,  according   to  the   data  from   the  government's   National
Statistical Offic  e, this   type of employment  is  currently classified
under the category of regula r employment.  Thus, the Ministry of Labor's
data are the only source available  to estimate  the number of fi.ed-term
and irregular workers. But, even in the da ta of the Ministry of Labor, a
fi.ed-term worker is narrowly defined  as "a work er  employed by a labor
contract of   less than  one  month." In   reality, it  is  comm on   that
fi.ed-term workers have contracts of  less than three, si.,  or twelve mo
nths, not only one month.  Therefore, we should be  aware that the number
of fi.e  d-term and   irregular employees estimated   in the Ministry   of
Labor's data may ha ve  been greatly underestimated. While  the number of
female regular employees in creased by 37.0% from  1,040 in 1981 to 1,425
in 1993, that of male regular empl oyees increased drastically by 105.5%.
Among wage earners,  female workers  incre ased by  125.5% from  2,082 to
4,695. Meanwhile, male workers increased  by 68.1%  during the  same time
period. Thus, it can  be confirmed that though  the rate of   increase in
female wage earners was much higher than that for male wage earners , the
rate of increase in female regular employees was relatively low and fi.ed
-term liregular employment was distributed mainly among female workers.

The previous studies(Korean Women's Association United  (1993).)  on the
actual situations of fi.ed-term  workers show low wages  and unstable emp
loyment as the main characteristics of  their jobs. First, when e.amining
the wa ges,  one can see  that fi.ed-term  workers were paid  lower wages
than  regular  wor   kers. However,   little  difference  e.ists   between
fi.ed-term and  full-time  worker s  in  the length   of service and   the
contents of work. Even when it  is assumed th at both  were paid the same
nominal wages, a wide  gap still remained terms  of th e  real wage level
because there   were such   large disparities   in bonuses,   retirem ent
allowances, social insurance costs, and welfare costs.
Second, when   e.amining the  employment  stability,  one can   see that
fi.ed-term wo rkers  faced the threat  of dismissal and  the necessity to
repeatedly  negotiate  s  hort-term  labor  contracts.  This   is because
fi.ed-term or irregular employment w as a major  tool for firms to adjust
their labor force in  case of business  fluct uations and  changes in the
economic environment.   Thus, firms  took  advantage  of   this type   of
contingent worker   in order  to secure   control over  the dismissal   of
employees. According   to a   study which   e.amined the   utilization of
contingent wo rk  force employment  in 600 S&M  firms, the  reasons firms
employ contingent worke  rs included  the following  in this  order- easy
recruitment and adjustment of the labor force, the advantage of obtaining
technical e.pertise and low wages. Amon g the reasons, the most important
was that firms wanted to  employ contingent wo rkers  to adjust the labor
force on a quantitative basis(Jung, In-su, 1995).
Although  it  is  unavoidable  because  of  its   nature for   fi.ed-term
employment to s uffer from unstable  employment, some protective measures
are urgently needed to  help full-timer fi.ed-term workers.  They are the
very class  of labor  which  shou ld  be converted  into  regular workers
because they  enter into   consecutive labor  contracts.   In fact, many
business practices have shown  that a fi.ed-term employ  ment contract of
less than si. or twelve months  is not terminated after the  ter m of the
contract has e.pired.  On the  contrary, the  worker enters  into another  
term, so   the contract   virtually becomes   equivalent to   a long-term
contract. How  ever, fi.ed-term  workers are  subject to  a contradictory
working status  as  so-ca lled,   fi.ed-term laborers,  while in   reality
providing the same long term servic e as regular workers.


3. Leased Work

Leased work   features a   trilateral contractual   relationships-  the
laborer, the  lease  firm which employs  the laborers,  and the firm  for
which leased laborers a re  used. Since leased work  is illegal under the
e.isting law with the e.ception  of a few cases  such as security guards,
janitors, etc., it  is harder to  investi gate the  precise situations of
leased workers than any other type of contingent employment. According to
the National Statistical  Office's Report  on establishm ent  census, the
number of firms  and employees  engaging in "manpower-leasing  bus iness"
was 398 and 8,814 respectively in 1986. However,  the number jumped to 1,
363 and 27,072 in 1991.  The Ministry of Labor estimated  that as of 1991
2,000 l ease  firms were  supplying about 100,000  leased workers  in the
following areas-  513  cleaning, 218  security guard,  815 building,  322
production-related, and 52  office management lease firms.
However, it is doubtful that such  official statistical data reflect the
e.act s ize of manpower-leasing businesses.  Quoting the estimations made
by the lease f irms themselves, Jung, In-su  and Yoon, Jin-ho (1993) said
that including such s  imple services as security  guard, cleaning, etc.,
400,000 to 500,000 workers we re engaging in leased work.
According to the 1992 research on the situations of five lease firms and
751 le ased  workers, legal  work such as  security guard,  cleaning, and
loading and unlo ading  had been the  main work for  leased workers until
1992. However, leased  job s  are recently being  found in  such ordinary
jobs as   production and  office work    or in  jobs  contracted through
employment  agencies  such   as interpretation,   trans  lation,   typing,
housekeeping service, and nursing. The research also  showed tha t 40% of
the total leased workers  were in office jobs.  The rest were,  in the fo
llowing order, in facility maintenance, casual labor, technical jobs, and
drivi ng. Then, among  the total leased  workers in office  jobs, 75% was
female. In  inv estigating  in  detaile, the  jobs of  the  leased female
office workers, we can see  that they engaged in  general office work and
office assistant work, document re ceiving and ushering, office equipment
manipulation, and accounting. All of  the se jobs used  to be occupied by
low-rank regular workers.(Jung, In-su and Yo on, Jin-ho (1993).)
  In the 1995 survey with 538 leased workers,  it was seen that they were
largely occupied in such jobs as  facility maintenance and repair, office
work and offic e assistant work, security guard, telephone-answering, and
ushering. Also, the  survey asked who had previously  engaged in the same
jobs that leased workers  we re performing and  discovered the phenomenon
that leased workers had been replac  ing regular workers.(Cho Soon-kyung,
"Ten Myths of Leased Work and Its Real  ity," Paper presented in the Open
Hearing, The  General  Preparatory Committee   of Democratic Labor   Union
(GPCDL), October 25, 1995.)

The wage levels of leased workers are not  parallel with that of regular
workers who have similar  qualifications as leased  workers. The research
conducted by Ju ng, In-su and Yoon, Jin-ho  (1993) revealed that male and
female leased workers  were paid 73.5% and 68.8%  of the wages of regular
workers, respectively. In Cho , Soon-kyung's research (1995), the percent
was only 60.3.  According to  the res ults  of Song,  Da-young's research
(1991), the wage level of female leased worke rs was merely about 50%-60%
that of female regular  workers who performed  the sa me  tasks. The wage
gap was also  widened by the  differences in bonuses,  lunch al lowances,
and job allowances rather than by the differences in basic wages.
According to Cho,  Soon-kyung's survey  (1995), 61.7% of  leased workers
had provi ded  their services  in the  same workplace  for more  than one
year; one-third of t hem had worked in the same place for more than three
years.
This finding challenges  the validity  of the  argument that  firms hire
leased wor kers mainly for  contingent tasks in order  to react to market
changes swiftly an  d fle.ibly. Of  the total leased  workers, only 18.2%
responded that they  believe d that  it was  possible for them  to become
regular workers. This  small response   also weakens the  grounds of  the
assertion that newly employed workers can becom e regular workers if they
are provided with job information and educational tra ining.
Since a client user-firm can dismiss  leased workers simply by canceling
its con tract with a lease firm, leased  workers are highly vulnerable to
a seriously un stable  state of employment. In  Cho, Soon-kyoung's survey
(1995), 64.1% of the t  otal leased workers answered  that a leased labor
contract had been suspended  by the one-sided decision  of user-firms. It
is believed  that such  employment unsta  bility of  leased workers  is a
natural consequence   of employment  practices  which take   advantage of
leased works  as  tools to   adjust the  quantity of  the  labor for   ce.
According to the research findings as to  the reasons firms employ leased
wo rkers, firms hired leased  workers for the following  purposes: out of
100%, 46.7 % to reduce wage costs; 22.4% to prepare for temporary changes
in labor demand; 13.3% to facilitate easy labor relations, and convenient
dismissal of  leased wo  rkers;9.7% to  provide technical  knowledge; and
7.9% to  meet other  needs(Jung, I  n-su and  Yoon, Jin-ho,  1993). Song,
Da-young's research (1991) shows that in th e  case of the securities and
insurance industry leased workers were introduced   on a full-scale basis
after 1987, when the  labor movement became  active. This i  s an obvious
e.ample to illustrate  that a leased  work system was  introduced for the
purpose of suppressing worker demands.
Furthermore, as we  have seen earlier,  70% of leased  workers could not
avoid con tracting leased jobs  because there were few  regular jobs left
for them. However , they did  not want to leave as  leased workers and so
most  of   them  worked   invol  untarily.  Therefore,   their  level   of
satisfaction was  naturally very   low (Jung,  In-su   and Yoon, Jin-ho,
1993). Cho, Soon-kyung found that 63.5% of the leased w orkers engaged in
such jobs because  they could not  find regular  jobs. The highe  r their
education, the higher  the ratio was.  Of the total  leased workers 82.2%  
complained about their working conditions. In response to the question as
to wh ether they  wanted to continue working  at the leased  jobs, 75% of
the total answ ered that they hoped to become regular workers(1995).
When we combine the results  of the surveys concerning  the situation of
leased w orkers, we can conclude that the  number of leased jobs e.panded
mainly because  of the firms' need. This development produced unfavorable
side effects  such as   the substitution  of leased  workers for  regular
workers, the unstable employment  of leased workers, the  division of the
labor market, the  abuse of leased  worker s, the  deterioration of their
wage and working conditions, and so on.
To improve  the inferior  working conditions  of leased   workers and to
establish t he stable employment conditions for them, systematic supports
should be  put int  o  place. However,  two viewpoints  are  currently in
bitter conflict over the  legi slation of  a leased labor  law. Those who
advocate it assert that the  enactment  of leased labor  law will protect
the workers, but those who reject it contend t hat the strict prohibition
of leased work is a  better way to shield  workers if  there is  a chance
for the legislation to stimulate the e.pansion of leased work .
The government  announced in  December 1993  that it   would legislate a
labor-relat ed law  entitled "A  Bill Relating to  the Regulation  of the
Manpower-Leasing Busi  ness and   to the Protection  of  Leased Workers."
However, the   approval of   the bil  l  has  been detained   because the
different viewpoints  were in   strong confrontion on   the issue of   the
current legislation. The bill is  again before a regular  ses sion of the
National Assembly.
With the  support  of the   Korea Employer's  Federation, the   advocates
maintain tha t a leased  labor law should be  legislated. They claim that
leased  work   has been   created  by   the autogenous   needs  of   labor
market-demand and supply-and  fulfills  the following  economic functions
in the labor market. First,  the use of leased  work  provides firms easy
access to a certain labor force which is demanded in t echnical fields or
for firms  to perform  technical functions.  Additionally, when  a sudden
surge in the demand for labor occurs, leased work helps firms to use t he
manpower fle.ibly. Thus,  the cost of  labor can be  reduced. Second, the
publi c job networks of the Korean labor  market are not efficient enough
to connect f  irms and laborers  in the  current market situations.  So a
leased work system can enlarge  the demand and supply  of the labor force
and consequently  curtail  the t   ransitional costs  by connecting   both
parties through private lease firms. Third , it is not easy for unskilled
laborers to enter the labor market. For them, th e leased work system can
offer an  opportunity for  on-the-spot training.  Fourth, as  a secondary
labor market,   leased work   provides an   idle labor   force with   oppo
rtunities  to   find  jobs.   Thus,  it  can   create  opportunities   for
employment.(Nam, Sung-il (1993) and Park, Joon-sung (1993).)

However, it is  doubtful that  these positive roles  of leased  work are
applicable to the  Korean labor  market. Judged from  the results  of the
above surveys, the  r esponses of  workers are mostly  negative. Even the
Western countries' e.perience s  with leased work systems  have not found
that the system can play  positive fun ctional roles  in the labor supply
and demand mechanism.  In fact, since  the user -firms  always manipulate
the system for their own convenience, it has been foun d to play negative
roles such as "hiring and firing" workers, dividing  workers  into a core
and a peripheral group, and disturbing employment stability in the  labor
market.(Lee, Kwang-taek (1993).)

For e.ample, three out of  four Japanese leased workers  are females who
do unski lled jobs  such as office automation  equipment manipulation and
document filing.
Only  30%  of   these female   workers  are  registered  for   employment
insurance. In ad  dition to  this, the  right to work  is not  secured in
Japan because maternity lea ve and childcare  leave are not guaranteed in
principle for female  leased worker s.  Furthermore, employment insurance
is cancelled in Japan upon delivery. In 19  86, when the leased labor law
was enacted, the number of leased workers was  80, 000 in Japan. However,
the number increased four times to 310,000 in 1989. Sinc e 1992, when the
economy entered into recession, leased labor  contracts have se ldom been
renewed and the effective job-offer  rate dropped several times.  All o f
these factors have caused leased  workers to be the first  on the list to
be sa   crificed by  employment  adjustment.(Danaka Humiko   and Kubaouku
(1994), pp .46-47.)

As observed in 1993, when  the leased labor law  was about to legislated
in Korea ,  it was not  desirable to  introduce a system,  especially one
like the Japanese  leased labor  system, without adapting it.  We need to
deeply consider  the lesson  s learned  from the   e.periences of foreign
countries. There are valid severe cri ticisms of the Japanese law because
it leaves   outside its  jurisdiction such   mat ters  as regulating   the
intermediary   commission  which   is   the   major  issue   concern   ing
worker-leases,  securing  the   wages of   workers,  and  regulating   the
cancellati on of lease contracts.(Lee, Kwang-taek (1993).)
  Japanese law pays little attention to the protection of leased workers'
rights . It  is now confirmed  that a legal  step to curb  the e.ploitive
practices, which have prevailed for the past ten years in Japan since the
enactment of the lease d labor law, are  hard to implement on a practical
level. Thus, Japanese are sug gesting that the law be amended.
Since the 1990s there has been a rise in the demand that job information
and em ployment agencies be  left to the free  market mechanism following
the trend of d eregulation. However, because they are believed to possess
the nature   of public   goods, it  is  predicted  that the   free market
mechanism may have a high  probabili ty of failure.  Thus, the government
should first reinforce its functions to  sta bilize the employment. After
that, the free  labor market mechanism  should be cu  ltivated to enhance
its efficiency.
It is recommended  that the government  should not attempt  to hurriedly
legislate  the  lease  law,  which  has  repeatedly   caused controversy.
Instead, the government should concentrate its full efforts on setting up
electronic data networks  conc erning  (un)employment and  available jobs
throughout the nation  on the basis  of  the employment  insurance system
that came into  effect from July  this year.  Such networks will  be more
efficient than lease firms in matching labor supply and d emand.
On the other hand, as the labor advocates that oppose the legislation of
lease  law contend(The major reason  to oppose the legislation  of Leased
Labor L aw is the anticipation that the legislation cannot really protect
leased worker s  but will  only result  in the  mass production  of these
workers.) we need to think about whether or not outlawing leased work can
prevent the fu rther e.pansion of leased laborers.
The number  of leased  workers is  e.pected to  grow in   spite of being
outlawed, un fortunately.  It is,  thus, undesirable to  continue leaving
leased workers withou t legal protection. If  the leased labor law should
be legislated for the protec  tion of the leased  workers themselves, the
following requirements must be satis fied- strengthening the requirements
for lease-firms,   strict regulation   for the   duration of   the lease,
clarifying the whereabouts  of the  user's responsibility  between  lease
firms and   user firms.(For   more specific   data on   the legisl   ation
direction for the Leased Work Law, see Lee, Eun-young (1992), Lee, Kwang-
taek (1993), and Kim, So-young (1995).)
  However, it is not easy  to legally supervise these  clauses of the law
to deter mine whether or not they are actually practiced after the law is
legislated. Ge rmany recently inserted "a  clause concerning using leased
workers" in the Law o f the Labor-Management  Council and made all rights
stipulated  in  the   law equall   y  applicable  to  workers   leased by
user-firms. This will be a  relatively easy wa y  to ascertain whether or
not the working conditions for leased workers is appr opriate and whether
leased work e.pands recklessly.
The findings  of studies   on contingent types   of employment, such   as
part-time, f i.ed-term, and leased work, have been analyzed so far in the
previous chapters.
Their results suggest that the  number of such workers  is increasing in
each typ e  of contingent employment,  and the phenomenon  is penetrating
into various indu  stries. It  is especially  conspicuous in  office jobs
mainly because firms alloca  te contingent workers to  simple office jobs
when office automation is becoming  increasingly  prevalent throughout in
the economy. In addition, the supply side   factor is another contributor
encouraging the increase  in contingent  employment because  the workers'
preference for  office jobs  results  in an  e.cessive supply   of  white
collar labor. Eventually, these e.cessive laborers  cannot find jobs an d
as contingent workers, they suffer from  disadvantages in general working
con ditions including lower wages and unstable employment. Moreover, they
cannot ta   ke advantage  of the   fle.ible working  system  that is   the
original characteristic of  contingent jobs  because they work  mainly as
quasi-full-timers. Consequently,   most of   them remain   as involuntary
contingent workers  who hope  to  become full-t  imers. Thus,  it  is the
e.isting market mechanism for the mobilization of the la bor force cannot
adapt to the innate fle.ibility of contingent employment.



POLICY TASKS- THE STABILITYOF THE FEMALE EMPLOYMENT STRUCTURE

In the   West, the  theory of   "labor fle.ibility"  has been   carefully
developed on  the  basis of a  long history  during which employment  was
guaranteed. The theory   mainly focuses  on how to  balance labor  market
fle.ibility with workers' rights.
Fle.ibility was  demanded  to be  able  to swiftly   react to the   rapid
changes in   th e  world's economic   environment. The  first reason   why
European countries were re luctant to take direct steps to activate labor
fle.ibility was that they were  n ot sure that  as fle.ibility increased,
the rate  of unemployment  would drop.  The second  reason was  that they
feared that  as fle.ibility  increased, negative  aspe cts  would surface
such as  an increasing  rate of  unemployment, the  wage losses   b y the
unemployed, the obstacles in the career path of young workers, diminishin
g motivation to work, and uncertain prospects for regular employment.
To overcome the high rate  of unemployment in Western  societies, it was
suggeste d that complementary measures for  employment be fle.ible. Thus,
quantitative fl e.ibility  policies were implemented,  such as curtailing
and restructuring worki  ng hours,  early retirement, and  increasing the
number of   contingent jobs.   As a   result,  an  appropriate level   of
protection  was  guaranteed  to  promote  the  workin   g conditions   and
employment stability of contingent workers.
It is  informative to  study the  conte.ts out  of which  European labor
fle.ibility policies   evolved because  there  was  a need   to introduce
countermeasures for the  lingering high rate of unemployment. However, in
Korea the demand and supply  fo rces in the labor  market should first be
balanced because the  labor market suff  ers from only  a slight sectoral
shortage in  the labor  force. It  would be  foolis h  to think  of labor
fle.ibility as  a  cut-and-dried way  to  solidify and   to enhan ce   the
national competitiveness, merely because the West's  labor market is emph
asizing such   fle.ibility. Korean  society  has  a weak   foundation for
employment s tability.  Furthermore, measures  to enhance  the employment
stability for  the con   tingent workers are  virtually  none.istent. The
lesson learned from the West's e .periences tells us that it is too early
for Korea to consider labor force fle.
ibility as   the most   urgent task   for the   Korean labor   market to
undertake. It wi  ll be an  appropriate task only  after a fair  level of
protections for contingent workers are in place.
The unstable trend of female employment is becoming more visible and the
prospe ct is e.pected  to become worse.  Therefore, it is  very urgent to
take steps   to e  stablish  a  stable  employment structure   for female
workers. To do so, fundamenta l countermeasures  should first be drawn up
to correct  the current  situation, wh  ere the  quantitative fle.ibility
strategy is impacting female workers at large.
It is  necessary to  search for   ways to set  up plans   to foster core
laborers thro   ugh the   development of   female workers'   competencies.
Second, some adequate  prot ective plans  should be laid  out for workers
who chose   contingent jobs  voluntari  ly  or involuntarily.   Last, the
coverage of   the employment   insurance system,   whi ch   was put   into
effective from July 1995,  should be e.panded  to help to  stabili ze the
employment of contingent workers, and effective  public job training prog
rams and solid work systems should be set up.


《REFERENCES》

Blank, R. M. (1990),  "Understanding Part-time Work."  Research in Labor
Economic s, Vol. 2.
Brodsky,   M.  M.   (1994),  "Labor   Market   Fle.ibility-  A   Changing
International Pers pective," Monthly Labor Review, November.
Cho, Soon-kyung,  "Ten Myths   of Leased Work   and Its Reality,"   Paper
presented in the  Open Hearing  by The  General Preparatory  Committee of
Democratic Labor (GPCD L), October 25, 1995.
Danaka, Humiko and Kubaouku (1994), The  Feminizaion of the Labor Force-
The Twe nty- First Century's Part-Time Work, Ubaigaku Press.
Dercksen, W. (1994), "Job Protection and Fle.ibility In Western Europe,"
In Lab or Relations in a Changing Environment Edited by A. Gladstone, et.
al. Walter d e Gruyter.
Houseman, S.  N. (1990),  "The Equity  and Efficiency   of Job Security-
Contrasting Perspectives on Collective Dismissal Laws in Western Europe,"
In New  Developmen ts  on the  Labor Market-  Toward a  New Institutional
Paradigm,  Edited by K.  G. A braham and  R. B. Mckersie.  Cambridge- The
MIT Press.
Jung, In-su   and Yoon,  Jin-ho (1993),   The Current  Situation of   the
Laborer-Lease Business and the Policy Tasks, Korean Labor Institute.
Korean Women's  Association for  Democracy and   Sisterhood (1995), "The
Situations and Policy Direction of Part-Time Work," Women Office Workers,
Spring Issue.
Korean Women's  Association United  (1993), A  Survey of  the Employment
Situations of Part-Time, Leased, and Fi.ed-Term Work.
Lee, Kwang-taek (1993), "Discussion on the  Legislation and Amendment of
the Lab or-Related Laws," Environment and Society (Fall Issue).
Nam, Sung-il   (1993), A   Study on   Leased Labor   in Korea,   Economic
Institute of So kang University.
OECD (1986), Fle.ibility in the Labor Market.
Osterman,  P.  and   T. A.   Kochan  (1990),  "Employment  Security   and
Employment Polic y- An Assessment  of the Issues, In  New Developments in
the Labor Market-  Toward a New  Institutional Paradigm, Edited  by K. G.
Abraham and R. B. Mckersie. Cambr idge- The MIT Press.
Park, Ha-soon (1992), "The Changes in the Personnel Management System of
Financ  ial  Institutions  and  the  Reaction  of   Labor Unions,"   Paper
presented in   the Foru  m  on the   Change in  the  Personnel System   of
Financial Institutions Sponsored  by  the  Korea Federation  of Bank  and
Finance Workers' Trade Union.
Park, Sung-joon (1993), Plans to Activate the Labor Lease System, Korean
Econom ic Research Institute.
Song, Da-young (1991), "Fi.ed Term Leased  Labor and Labor Regulations,"
Master' s Thesis, Ewha Womans University.
Szyszczak, E. (1990), Partial Unemployment- The Regulation of Short Time
Workin g in Britain, London- Mansell.




Posted by KWWA
|